A Coruña, Spain.
[dropcap style=»default, circle, box, book»]O[/dropcap]ver the past couple of decades there has been a lot of talk about Public – Private Partnerships, also known as Public – Private Associations (APP) or Cooperation (CCP) as model for the management and financing of infrastructures. Even in the early stages of the two governments presiding over the economic downturn in Spain, the idea that these were the solutions to the problem of the lack of public resources still was widely voiced.
And before the aforesaid economic downturn a large number of projects were developed during the first decade of the twenty-first century known as PPP. Yet the problem is that the term is somewhat vague that many fail to grasp or misuse. Furthermore, no critical analysis on its operational effectiveness has been performed. For this reason, I have decided to write what will be a trilogy on the matter. I believe that there is a lot of mileage in this issue, and so, depending on the debate created, perhaps all this will bring about the “Decameron” of the PPPs.
The three articles will be the following:
- This, the first one, which as you can see is entitled: Public – Private Partnerships. Who pays for and who finances our infrastructures? In which we will focus our attention on basic concepts essentially. This aspect may be necessary for others to understand the following instalments.
- The second is entitled “What are the pros and cons of Public – Private Partnerships (PPP)?
- Finally, I will share some conclusions with you based on a research project I was involved in some years ago in a post entitled “The influence of political ideology on the Financing and Management Models used for large-scale infrastructure projects”
Let us then begin with some basic concepts: What is a PPP? These are formulae for the participation of the private sector in the development of a public service (transport, health, water, etc) which may be seen in a variety of ways, the most commonplace being concessions for building and operation. [pullquote align=»right»]These tender projects have always existed, but the difference is that generally the risks and whole responsibility are transferred to the private sector, up to the point that the latter realised that this made the projects unfeasible or of little interest socially.[/pullquote] For this reason the concept of the PPP so that a tender project always had a contribution from the public sector so that this can acquire vastly different forms.
Problems in the application of concessions for public transport infrastructures in urban environments stem largely from the fact that these projects that form part of a complex area involving interactions that are often difficult to control. This implies enormous costs, and for this reason, tender projects of this type use mixed models, that is public and private sector participation, as we have already mentioned.
In Spain, the Concessions Act, passed in 2003 to Regulate Concession Contracts for Public Works (now duly derogated and with its provisions now included in the Law of Public Service Contracts passed in 2007) established a new legal framework, whose main characteristics are the:
- Maintaining the basic concepts of a Concession, the procedure for the awarding of the same and respecting the existing specialities for the regulations and legislation in place expanding the concession model for all public works and implementing this for all Public Sector Administration and Public Office Bodies compliant with the same.
- Establishment of public aid may be in the form of financial contributions or not, and the winning bidder may be reimbursed with the price paid for the usage of the project and returns associated with the development of the area adjacent to the infrastructure.
- Establishment of the possibility of using the concept of a “shadow toll regime” and cross-financing for different projects involving public works whenever these have a functional relationship and incidence in terms of their respective operation.
- Establishment of the obligation to restore the economic balance when this has been notably altered (in both senses).
- Regulation of the financing systems on the part of the contract awarder in terms of the issuance of obligations and other titles, the use of assets, concession mortgaging and a loan with participation in the equity.
- Definition of a maximum timeframe of 40 years for tenders relating to the construction and operation of public works and 20 for those dealing with operation tenders.
- Setting of a progress clause that demands the adaptation of the tender to advances over time in relation to legislation and technolog.
So why did these multiply so rapidly in recent years, above all in Spain?
This will be looked at in more detail in forthcoming posts, yet an important reason for this can be found in the fact that it was a means of aiming to avoid creating a deficit in public sector investments.
In the diagram below we can see the schema that the EU contemplated for the consideration of investments as being public:
DECISION TREE
Figura 2.5: Decision Tree for the evaluation of accountancy of a debt in anPPP.
Source: EIB 2004
And to end this first post on PPPs I would like to clarify a topic that many politicians and the press muddle up when talking about the issue. There are two concepts: Who pays for the infrastructures?And who finances them?
Financing (the putting forward to the money) normally comes from Financial Institutions (Banks, Investment Funds etc.), from companies awarding concessions or the Public Sector Administration itself. Though they never pays, the payers could be:
- All of the citizens through taxations.
- The users of the services, either fully or with partial subsidies.
- The beneficiaries of an investment. For example, if a Metropolitan Railway Line is built that passes through a business district or that will serve a future residential development. This could be paid for (at least partially) by taxes on the beneficiary companies (as in the case of the French case, Versement). Or, alternatively, the construction creates added value to the urban development paid for by those purchasing a property or business premises in the aforementioned area.
I will leave you with a link to my doctoral thesis on PPP in the field of urban and metropolitan transport, though we will continue to talk about the usefulness and opportunities offered by PPPs for the development of infrastructures.
And so it is time to leave the floor open to my readers, and, to get the ball rolling, here are a couple of things to mull over in the meantime. Are PPPs the solution for the creation of new investments in times of financial shortfall? Do you agree with the PPP programmes for the privatisation of health services? Do these bring savings?